y157Εz
Lessons
from the Inoue Zaisei and the Takahashi Zaisei
Kikuo Iwata, Yasushi Okada, Seiji Adachi and Yasuyuki Iida
Introduction1
Since the 1992 recession, the performance of the Japanese
economy has been the worst of the developed nations. Japanfs average rate of
real economic growth was only 1.1% between 1992 and 2001, compared with 4.0%
growth in the 1980s. The comparable figures for
A number of hypotheses have emerged, including the
inadequacy of fiscal policy, inappropriate monetary policy leading to
deflation, the low investment rate following over-investment during the bubble
period of the late 1980s and early 1990s, financial disintermediation due to
huge nonperforming loans, and a fall in the potential growth rate because of
supply-side factors.
In an attempt to repair the economy, the then Prime
Minister Keizo Obuchi from
1998 until 2000 substantially increased government expenditures and cut both
income and corporate taxes. The result was a huge increase in the stock of
government bonds. In contrast, for the past three years, the then Prime
Minister Junichiro Koizumi from 2001 untill 2006 largely reduced government expenditures and
tried to improve the supply side of the Japanese economy. Koizumi was confident
that regulated and inefficient public enterprises and financial corporations
were responsible for Japanfs poor performance in the 1990s. Therefore, he
intended to regenerate the Japanese economy by implementing structural reforms,
including deregulation and privatization of public enterprises and financial
corporations. Such economic reforms were undertaken in developed countries such
as the
However, we doubt whether the structural reforms
succeeded in regenerating the Japanese economy. There had been a large
deflationary gap in the Japanese economy since 1998, and it was highly likely
that the structural reforms enlarged this gap by raising the potential growth
rate. If so, it is less likely that the structual
reforms are the cause of the economic recovery since 2002.
It should be noted that the developed countries,
including the
No country had experienced deflation in the postwar
period until the Japanese economy did so in 1998. However, in the 1930s, many
countries, including
This paper examines the Takahashi Zaisei
in order to throw light on the causes of the prolonged stagnation
1 How
1-1 The Inoue Zaisei
that caused the Shouwa Kyou
Kou
Inoue Zaisei
as a Deflationary Regime
We evaluate economic policies from the perspective of the
policy regimes adopted by policy agents. A policy regime is the framework that
determines the rules of the game in which economic agents participate. It is
systematic and hence predictable. Economic agents would not respond to policies
that are inconsistent with the policy regime, but only to those that are
consistent with it.
Then, we examine which policy regime resulted in the Shouwa Kyou Kou(the
Shouwa Great Depresion).
From the outbreak of World War I in 1914 until 1919,
the Japanese economy boomed because of a huge trade surplus. However, at the
end of the war, the trade surplus was reduced rapidly and
The then Minister of Finance, Jyunnosuke
Inoue, who took office in 1929, was confident that structural y159Εzproblems gave
rise to the prolonged stagnation of the 1920s. He believed that inflation
should have been lowered, the exchange rate increased, and inefficient firms
liquidated. Therefore, he decided to appreciate the exchange rate to its prewar
level by returning to the gold standard system that had been suspended since
the beginning of the WWI. In addition, he adopted tight monetary and fiscal
policies in order to lower the general price level. The end result was the Shouwa Kyou Kou. This economic
policy is called Inoue Zaisei (Inoue Economic Policy)
after the Minister of Finance.
The Inoue Zaisei policy
regime was one of deflation, based on inefficient firm liquidations and the
return to the gold standard. According to Schumpeterfs creative destruction
hypothesis, creative firms will appear only after inefficient firms are
removed. Inoue believed that the liquidation of the inefficient firms would
allow the Japanese economy to regenerate through the so-called Schumpeterian
process of creative destruction.
1-2 The
Change of the Economic Policy Regime by Takahashi
Takahashi Zaisei
as a Reflationary Regime
As Inoue Zaisei caused an
economic disaster, Tsuyoshi Inukai took over the
reins of government and appointed Korekiyo Takahashi
as Minister of Finance. Takahashi immediately suspended the gold standard
system and then issued public bonds to finance increased public expenditures.
In addition, he had the Bank of Japan buy public bonds directly from the
government. This increased the money supply at the same time as public
expenditures increased. Thus, Takahashifs regime involved not only expansionary
fiscal policy but also easy monetary policy, even though this policy is called
Takahashi Zaisei (Takahashi Fiscal Policy).
Chart 1 shows that, as the
ratio of public bonds held by the Bank of Japan increased, the deflation ended
and mild inflation developed. The average rate of growth of the money supply
rose from negative 4.2% for 1930-1931 to 5.6% for the period 1932-1935 (see
table 1).
When Takahashi was assassinated in February 1936, the
A Two-Step Change of the Policy
Regime
We trace in detail the process in which the deflation
was ended and inflation developed.
Takahashi suspended the gold standard system on 13
December 1931 and returned to a floating exchange system, with the result that
the exchange rate depreciated from $49 per yen to $20-30 per yen (see chart 2).
The retail price began to rise. Therefore, it seemed that the deflation had
ended. This was the first step of the Takahashi reflationary
policy.
However, some people may have been disappointed that
Takahashi did not take advantage of the suspension of the gold standard to
adopt an easy monetary policy stance. This unrealized expectation may have been
the cause of the decline of stock prices (see chart 3) and the revival of
deflation (see chart 2). Then, on 15 May 1932, the 5.15 coup dfetat occurred, in which then Prime Minister Inukai was assassinated,y160Εz and this was followed by a steep plunge in
confidence about the economy (chart 2).
In November 1932, against the background of these
circumstances, Takahashi resolved to adopt an easy monetary policy under which
the Bank of Japan directly underwrote public bonds issued by the government.
This direct underwriting of public bonds is called a monetization policy. This
was the second step of the Takahashi reflationary
policy and it completely ended the deflation (see chart 2).
The Change of the Expected
Inflation Rate caused by the Policy Regime Change
According to chart 3, the stock price had risen substantially
before the gold standard system was suspended in December 1931. Charts 2 and 3
show that the stock and the retail prices started to rise
in August 1932, before the Bank of Japan began to directly underwrite the
public bonds issued by the government in November of that year. This suggests
that inflationary expectations had already developed before the suspension of
the gold standard system or the start of the direct underwriting of issued
public bonds by the Bank of Japan.
The change of the policy regime to a reflationary regime would first raise the expected rate of
inflation, which in turn would raise stock and land prices, and then the actual
rate of inflation. Finally, both the nominal and the real rate of economic
growth would rise. We investigate further when inflationary expectations
developed under the Takahashi Zaisei.
Okada and Iida (2004) estimated the expected rate of
inflation in the 1920s and 1930s by using the interest rate model developed by Mishkin (1992). They found the following:
(1) The
expected rate of inflation rose to a positive figure in September 1931, before
the suspension of the gold standard system in December 1931 (chart 4). In
September 1931, the Manchurian incident broke out and
(2) However,
the expected rate of inflation began to decrease after the suspension of the
gold standard system in December 1931. This may have been because an easy
monetary policy was not adopted. The expected rate of inflation suddenly
increased again in April 1932, after Takahashifs announcement in March of that
year that, in the near future, he intended to adopt the policy under which the
Bank of
The effects of inflationary expectations
Let us consider how the development of inflationary
expectations following Takahashifs reflationary
policy regime stimulated the Japanese economy and saved it from the economic
crisis.
(1) The reduced expected real
interest rate
As long as the nominal interest rate does not rise as
much as the expected rate of inflation does, the expected real interest rate
falls2. Chart 5 shows that the expected real
interest rate during the Takahashi y161ΕzZaisei period was
much lower than just before and during the Shouwa Kyou Kou period.
This reduction in the expected real interest rate
increased both investment and durable consumption expenditures to raise Gross
Domestic Product (GDP).
(2) The improvement in the balance sheet
The increase of the expected rate of inflation raised
stock and land prices (see chart 3). Those increases improved the balance
sheets of firms and households, which may have increased their expenditures.
(3) The increase of equity finance
The rise of stock prices greatly increased
equity finance (see chart 6), which encouraged the establishment of new firms
(see chart 7).
Chart 8 shows that the number of corporations being
established decreased during the deflationary period, whereas it increased
during the inflationary period.
We infer from these facts that the hypothesis of a
Schumpeterian creative destruction process is not supported.
1-3 Other Hypotheses about the
Recovery from the Shouwa Kyou
Kou
We now consider alternative hypotheses about the
recovery from the Shouwa Kyou
Kou.
The Reduced Nonperforming Loans
Hypothesis
It has been claimed that the Japanese economy
stagnated during the 1920s because of the financial disintermediation that
resulted from the huge nonperforming loans. From this point of view, the Takahashi
Zaisei succeeded in regenerating the Japanese economy
only because the Shouwa Kinyou
Kyou Kou (the Shouwa Bank
Crisis, not to be confused with the Shouwa Kyou Kou) removed almost all of the nonperforming loans in
1927.
Adachi (2004) disputed this hypothesis by indicating
that new nonperforming loans increased remarkably during 1930-31 the Shouwa Kyou Kou period, even
though many earlier loans were reduced in 1927.
Chart 9 shows that industrial output increased rapidly
during the Takahashi Zaisei period, whereas bank
loans were reduced. Thus, the financial disintermediation problem was not
solved during the Takahashi Zaisei period. However,
the Japanese economy succeeded in escaping from the Great Depression. The
question is why.
Chart 10 shows that the corporations had abundant
internal funds during the Shouwa Kyou
Kou period and could therefore finance their own investment expenditures.
Another way of financing expenditures was by issuing
equity, as shown above (see chart 10).
Corporations recovering from the Great Depression in
the
y162ΕzThe
Fiscal Policy Hypothesis
Another claim is that the Japanese economy recovered
from the Shouwa Kyou Kou
because of the combined effects of fiscal policy and the Pacific Ocean War.
In July 1935, Takahashi made the following comments on
the public bond policy:
(1) A
large amount of public bonds have been issued since the 1932 fiscal year. So
far, this public bond policy has resulted in a decline of the interest rate
aimed at restoring the economy.
(2) However,
we will not be able to issue public bonds to the extent that we have done in
the past. Excess issues cause an inflationary spiral and financial bankruptcy,
as shown by the experiences of European countries after WWI.
Charts 13 and 14 show that both the military
budget and the balance of long-term public bonds increased considerably in
fiscal years 1932 and 1933, during the first half of the Takahashi Zaisei. However, the growth rates of both decreased
substantially in fiscal years 1934 and 1935, the second half of the Takahashi Zaisei.
As the Japanese economy had already recovered from the
crisis by 1933, Takahashi attempted to reduce the government budgets from that
fiscal year. In February 1936, he was assassinated in the 2.26 coup dfetat by the military, which strongly demanded an increase
in its portion of the budget.
The next Minister of Finance, Eiichi Baba, adopted an
inflationary economic policy that increased the military budget as much as the
military demanded. He had the Bank of Japan directly underwrite public bonds to
finance the budget.
Charts 13 and 14 show that both the military
budget and the balance of long-term public bonds increased enormously after the
end of the Takahashi Zaisei in the 1935 fiscal year.
The average rate of real economic growth was 4.5% and
inflation was around 10% for the period from 1936 to 1940, whereas these rates
were 7.2% and 2.0%, respectively, during the Takahashi Zaisei.
The ratio of real consumption expenditures to real GDP, which indicates living
standards, dropped to less than 60% in 1940, whereas it was about 72% during
the Takahashi Zaisei.
Hence, we conclude as follows:
(1) The
fiscal policy hypothesis that the Takahashi Zaisei
succeeded in recovering from the Shouwa Kyou Kou by a huge increase in the fiscal budget is not
supported.
(2) The
Pacific Ocean War did not finally save the Japanese economy from the Shouwa Kyou Kou. Instead, it
completely ruined the economy.
2 Lessons from the Shouwa Kyou Kou
We now consider what lessons we should learn from the Shouwa Kyou Kou that may throw
light on the causes of the prolonged stagnation of the Japanese economy in the
1990s and early 2000s, and what policies will sustain and stabilize growth.
Why the Takahashi Zaisei Succeeded
As long as deflationary expectations exist, the
expected real interest rate may not decrease to levels necessary to increase
both investment and durable consumption expenditures. This is due to downward y163Εzrigidity in
the nominal rate of interest. In addition, deflationary expectations may
decrease both the stock and land prices, worsening the balance sheets of firms
and households, with the result that their expenditures will decline.
Therefore, to restore the economy from stagnation, which arises from persistent
deflationary expectations, and to return to sustained and stable growth, the
expectation of deflation itself must be removed.
Section 1 shows that the reasons for the
success of the Takahashi Zaisei were the suspension
of the gold standard system accompanied by the direct underwriting of public
bonds by the Bank of Japan. This definite change of the policy regime to
a reflationary regime raised the expected rate of
inflation and stimulated the economy, as shown in section 1-2.
Eichengreen (1992) and Bernanke (2000) showed that the
If the persistent expectation of deflation is removed and
an expectation of mild inflation is established, the macroeconomy
would become stable. To change expectations, it is essential that the policy
regime is credible. Therefore, the policy agents should be strongly committed
to maintaining their policy regimes.
Policies for Sustained Economic
Growth
Since 1992, there have been fierce debates among
economists about the causes of Japanfs stagnation. These arguments, which have
continued for more than 10 years, can be categorized into two broad theories:
first, the argument that Japanfs structural problems were the cause of the
stagnation, and second, the argument that the Bank of Japanfs monetary policy,
which induced deflation, was to blame. In assessing the validity of these
arguments, it is worthwhile to reflect on these theories in the light of the
recovery from the Shouwa Kyou
Kou, as well as the more recent recovery that has occurred since 2002.
There are variations within the broad theory that
structural problems are the cause of the stagnation. The most typical argument
is that the banks were to blame because they were reluctant to advance new
loans, and extended forbearance lending. If the reluctance of banks to lend was
indeed the cause of the stagnation, economic recovery would require an increase
in the volume of bank loans. However, the Japanese economy began to recover in
2002, despite the fact that bank loans had been decreasing (chart 16). That is,
the recent recovery was achieved without an increase in bank lending, as was
the recovery from the Shouwa Kyou
Kou, and that of the
According to the proponents of the forbearance-lending
hypothesis, the economy remained suppressed as funds were absorbed by
forbearance lending and were unavailable to new businesses. However, during the
recovery of 2002-2004, sound firms utilized their own funds (chart 17). In
fact, firms in general repaid their bank loans just as firms did during the
recovery from the Shouwa Kyou
Kou and the Great Depression (charts 10 and 11).
Some supporters of the structural-problem hypothesis
claim that the recovery of 2002 was a result of the Koizumi reforms. However,
the Koizumi reforms were limited to laying the groundwork for privatization of
the Housing Loan Corporation and the Japan Highway Public Corporation during
2001-2004. It is difficult to relate those decisions to the recovery of the
economy. In addition, it is argued that the Koizumi governmentfs cuts in public
spending aided the recovery by encouraging the self-reliance of loy164Εzcal regions.
However, this is not a convincing argument.
Before examining the theory that deflationary
expectations caused the prolonged stagnation, we must correct the common
misconception that the economy cannot recover while deflation persists. There
are countless cases in history when relatively high growth was achieved in a
deflationary environment. The recoveries from the Shouwa
Kyou Kou and the Great Depression began before
deflation ended. In
Section 1 shows that it is necessary for
public sentiment to change from anticipating deflation to expecting inflation. This study
points to the necessity of a decline in expected real interest rates to a level
compatible with the realization of full employment, which in turn sets the
basis for sustained and stable growth. Hence, if deflation has not ended, but
the anticipation of future deflation ceases, or inflationary expectations
develop, expected real interest rates would fall, bringing about real economic
recovery. That is, we should distinguish between actual deflation and the
expectation of deflation. What is relevant to the performance of the macroeconomy is not actual deflation, but the expectation
of deflation.
Analyses of the behavior of the inflation-indexed
government bonds in the market indicated changes in 2006 in peoplefs sentiment
toward the future, in that they seemed to sense an end to the deflationary
trend. The reasons for this calming of deflationary sentiment were the heavy
intervention in the foreign exchange market by the Ministry of Finance that
occurred in 2003, and clear indications by the Bank of Japan that it was
committed to breaking away from deflation. The remarks by BOJ Governor Fukui
expressed a strong commitment to the fight against deflation, which had been
unexpected given Fukuifs words and actions before assuming the governorship.
However, despite this positive development, the expected
real interest rate has not yet reached the levels required to realize full
employment. For the expected real interest rate to drop to the required level,
inflationary expectations need to rise to around 2-3%. Therefore, the BOJ
should pursue an inflation target and show a strong commitment to attaining a
level of inflation within this range.
References
Adachi, Seiji(2004)hThe Problem of nonperforming loans
and the Transformation of the
Financial System during the Shouwa Great
Depressionh, in Kikuo Iwata, ed., Studies on the Shouwa Great Depression, Touyoukeizai Shinpousha, 2004 (in
Japanese).
Bernanke, B (2000) Essays on the Great Depression,
Bernanke, B (2003) gSome Thoughts on Monetary Policy in
Japan,h before the Japan Society of Monetary Economics, Tokyo, Japan, May, 31
Bernanke, B and Mark Gertler (1989) gAgency Costs, Net worth, and Business
Fluctuations,h American Economic Review,
Vol.79,No.1.
Bernanke, B and Mark Gertler (1990) gFinancial Fragility and Economic
Performance,h Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol.105, No.1.
y165ΕzBernanke, B and Mark Gertler (1999) gMonetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility,h
Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City, Forth Quarter.
Bernanke, B, et al. (2000) gDiscussion,h
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000,
Cabarello, Ricardo and Mohamad Hammour (2000) gCreative
Destruction and Development: Institutions, Crises, and Restructuring,h NBER Working Paper Series, No.7849.
Cecchetti, Stephen (1992) gPrices
during the Great Depression: Was the Deflation of 1930-1932 Really
Unanticipated?h American Economic Review,
Vol.82, No.1.
Eichengreen, Barry
(1992) Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard
and the Great Depression, 1919-1939,
Fisher, Irving (1933) gDebt-Deflation Theory of the
Great Depression,h Econometrica,
Vol.1, No.4.
Hamilton, James (1992) g Was the Deflation during the
Great Depression Anticipated?: Evidence From the Commodity Market,h American Economic Review, Vol.82, No.1.
Iwata, Kikuo, ed. (2004a), Studies on the Shouwa
Great Depression, Touyoukeizai Shinpousha, (in Japanese).
Iwata, Kikuo(2004b)h Lessons
from the Shouwa
Great Depression,h in Iwata, Kikuo, ed., Studies on the Shouwa
Great Depression, Touyoukeizai Shinpousha , 2004 (in Japanese).
Kiyotaki, N and John Moore
(1997) gCredit Cycles,h Journal of
Political Economy, Vol.105, No.2.
Krugman, Paul (1998) g Itfs Baaack: Japanese Slump and the Return of the Liquidity
Trap,h Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 2.
Mishkin, Frederic (1981) g The Real Interest Rate: An Empirical Investigation,h in K.
Brunner and Allan Meltzer, ed., The Cost
and Consequences of Inflation, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, Vol.14.
Okada, Yasushi and Yasuyuki
Iida (2004) gThe Shouwa Great Depression and an
Empirical Investigation into the Real Interest Rate,h in Kikuo
Iwata, ed., Studies on the Shouwa Great Depression, Touyoukeizai
Shinpousha, 2004 (in Japanese).
Romer, Christina (1992) gWhat Ended the Great Depression,h Journal of Economic History, VOL.92,
No.4.
Sargent, Thomas (1982) gThe
End of Four Big Inflations,h in Robert Hall, ed., Inflation: Causes and Effects,
Temin, Peter (1989) Lessons from the Great Depression,
y166Εz
y167Εz
y168Εz
y169Εz
y170Εz
y171Εz
y172Εz
y173Εz
y174Εz
y175Εz
y176Εz
y177Εz
y178Εz
y179Εz
y180Εz
y181Εz
y182Εz